Social spending and poverty

It’s commonly thought that a market-liberal political economy is best for the rich while a social-democratic one is best for the poor. Some recent research suggests reason to question this. Analyses by Willem Adema of the OECD, by Adema and Maxime Ladaique, and by Price Fishback conclude that the quantity of social expenditures in the United States is similar to or greater than in Denmark and Sweden, two nations long considered large-welfare-state exemplars.*

How so? Government social transfers account for a much larger share of GDP in Sweden and Denmark. But the U.S. government distributes more benefits in the form of tax breaks rather than transfers than do the two Nordic countries; Denmark and Sweden tax back a larger portion of public transfers than the United States does; private social expenditures, such as those on employment-based health insurance and pensions, are greater in the U.S.; and America’s per capita GDP is larger.

The standard indicator of social policy effort is gross public social expenditures as a percentage of GDP. Denmark and Sweden are much higher than the United States on this measure.

Now shift to net (rather than gross) public and private (rather than public alone) expenditures per person (rather than as a percentage of GDP, with purchasing power parities used to convert Danish and Swedish kroner into U.S. dollars). According to the calculations by Adema and Ladaique (Fishback’s are similar), we get a very different picture. By this measure the U.S. is the biggest spender.

This looks like good news for the poor in the United States. Is it? Unfortunately, no. These adjustments change the story with respect to the aggregate quantity of resources spent on social protection in the three countries, but they have limited bearing on redistribution and on the living standards of the poor.

Begin with tax breaks. Researchers count as “social” those designed to provide support in circumstances that adversely affect people’s well-being. In the United States these disproportionately go to the affluent and the middle class. The chief ones are tax advantages for employer and employee contributions to private health insurance and private pensions. These do little to help people at the low end of the distribution, who often work for employers that don’t provide health or retirement benefits. One valuable tax benefit for low-income households is the Earned Income Tax Credit (EITC), but it is already included in the standard OECD data on government social expenditures. Another is the child tax credit, but it is non-refundable and so of limited value to low-income households, many of whom don’t owe any federal income tax.

Next consider tax “clawbacks” in the Nordic countries. Public transfer programs in Denmark and Sweden tend to be “universal” in design: a large share of the population is eligible for the benefit. This is thought to boost public support for such programs. But it renders them very expensive. To make them more affordable, the government claws back some of the benefit by taxing it as though it were regular income. All countries do this, including the United States, but the Nordic countries do it more extensively. Does that hurt their poor? Very little. The tax rates tend to increase with household income, so much of the tax clawback hits middle- and upper-income households.

What’s the impact of private social spending? In the U.S. this accounts for roughly two-fifths of all social expenditures. It consists mainly of employer contributions to health insurance and employment-based pension benefits. Here too the picture changes a great deal on average, but not much for the poor. Employer-based health insurance and pension plans reach few low-income households.

So how well-off are the poor in the United States, with its “hidden welfare state,” compared to social-democratic Denmark and Sweden? One measure is average posttransfer-posttax (“disposable”) income among households in the bottom decile of the income distribution. Here are my calculations using the best available comparative data, from the Luxembourg Income Study (LIS). (The numbers are adjusted for household size. They refer to a household with a single adult. For a family of four, multiply by two.)

This is a pretty big difference, not in America’s favor.

In his paper, Fishback cites similar numbers from the OECD. He cautions, though, that “One advantage the poor Americans would have had in spending their disposable income is that they face consumption tax rates in the 4 to 7 percent range, while consumption taxes in the Nordic countries are above 20 percent.” Actually, consumption tax rates are incorporated in the purchasing power parities (PPPs) used to convert incomes to a common currency, so these income figures already adjust for differences in consumption taxes.

What’s the source of this cross-country difference in the incomes of low-end households? It’s entirely a function of government transfers. Again using the LIS data, I’ve calculated mid-2000s averages for households in the bottom income decile for the three chief sources of household income: earnings, net government transfers (transfers received minus taxes paid), and “other” income (money from family or friends, alimony, etc.). Average earnings are virtually identical across the three countries, at about $2,500. The same is true for “other” income, which averages around $500 in each of the three. Where bottom-decile Danish and Swedish households fare much better than their American counterparts is in net government transfers:

Fishback rightly points to one other key difference between these countries: “Public services not counted in disposable income, like health care and education, likely are better for the very poor in the Nordic countries than in the United States.” It’s difficult to measure the impact of services on living standards with any precision. One indirect way to assess their effect is to switch from income to material deprivation. Two OECD researchers, Romina Boarini and Marco Mira d’Ercole, have compiled material deprivation data from surveys in various rich nations as of the mid-2000s. Each of the surveys asked identical or very similar questions about seven indicators of material hardship: inability to adequately heat one’s home, constrained food choices, overcrowding, poor environmental conditions (e.g., noise, pollution), arrears in payment of utility bills, arrears in mortgage or rent payment, and difficulty in making ends meet. Boarini and Mira d’Ercole create a summary measure of deprivation by averaging, for each country, the shares of the population reporting deprivation on questions in each of these seven areas.

Government services — medical care, child care, housing, transportation, and so on — reduce material hardship directly. They also free up income to be spent on other needs. The comparative data, though by no means perfect, are consistent with the hypothesis that public services help the poor more in the Nordic countries than in the United States. The gap between the countries in material deprivation is larger than in low-end incomes.

Helping the poor is not, of course, the only thing we want from social spending. But it surely is one thing. The United States spends more money on social protection than is often thought, yet that spending doesn’t do nearly as much to help America’s poor as we might like.

For those interested, I’m finishing up a book manuscript that looks at this issue and related ones in more detail.

__________

* Related research: Adema, Garfinkel-Rainwater-Smeeding, Hacker, Howard. Blog commentary: Fishback, Salam, Schulz, Wilkinson, Yglesias.

12 thoughts on “Social spending and poverty

  1. The post tax post transfer incomes. How does this map over Tim Smeedings findings from the LIS? He calculates the incomes relative to US median incomes, which gives us figures for Finalnd and Sweden of about 38% of US median household income for the bottom decile while the US number is….37%.

    Clearly that’s a rather different result and I’d love to know which is more accurate.

  2. Tim:

    Depends on which Smeeding paper and year you’re referring to, but I presume the figures you mention are for the tenth percentile (P10) rather than the average for the bottom decile. There’s less difference across countries in the former. Here are my calculations from LIS data for P10 posttransfer-posttax incomes (all in 2000 US dollars per equivalent person):

    Denmark 2000: $11,600
    Sweden 2000: $9,000
    US 2000: $9,300

    Denmark 2004: $12,100
    Sweden 2005: $10,500
    US 2004: $9,100

    Lane

  3. Some questions:

    1. If we are comparing social spending as a share of GDP, isn’t the net figure clearly preferable to the gross one?

    2. Why present income in terms of PP dollars, rather than relative to the mean?

    3. Why limit our focus to the bottom decile? Why isn’t spending on the 2nd or 3rd decile relevant to the question of relative size of welfare states?

  4. It would be interesting to see these numbers for the top decile. I think that would make your point even stronger.

  5. Maybe this is already in the analysis, but another factor that has a large impact on poor people is the vast differences in availability and quality of public transportation. In most of Europe, this is subsidized to a considerable extent. Poor people disproportionally benefit, both from the subsidized costs, but also from the ability to get to the same shops as wealthier people. The phenomenon of high-priced shops located in poor areas, taking advantage of lack of mobility, is common in the US, but rare in Europe.

  6. *hopefully I read this article and understood the premises enough to comment.

    nice article, i loved it! it is a great comparison of wasting money on an ideal that has no basis(ie. tax cuts/tax rebates). but the premise that the overall transfer of wealth determines the more “social-democratic” a state is not correct. liberal economies use taxes to distribute wealth, while social democratic states use public programs (ie. More mass transportation, single payer health systems, free day-care, etc.). it is obvious by this comparison that using taxes to distribute wealth is ridiculous(which sort-of implies that the poor aren’t very good with money(it might be obvious to say this and a little harsh but it destroys the basis of liberal economist of rational players)). essentially,” tax and spend” is good while “tax and give back” fails.

    but i would also like to look at “developing” countries and social equality. Colombia(free-marketeer) vs Venezuela(evil socialist)*, it is clear that the more the rich have, the less the poor have. the dutch disease effect tells us that Venezuela would go to hell, in terms of inequality, but the exact opposite has happened since Hugo Chavez has gotten in control. the rich have become poorer, the poor have become richer. while the exact opposite has happened in Colombia, there has been no progress in social equality even though they are moving towards a market based economy.**

    *ultra conservative libertarian think tank ranks countries by most free market: http://www.heritage.org/index/Ranking.aspx

    **comparing Venezuela and Colombia in the last 10 years(since hugo chavez has gotten in control): http://tinyurl.com/venVSCol

  7. The introduction evoked feeling we will read some breaking news, but finally the result was quite ordinary: liberal economies are worse in terms of social ‘equality’

    1.How liberal the USA really are? According to ranking offered by previous commenter, Denmark is side by side with USA, Sweden and Norway are not lagging very much. There is also very interesting article on mises.org about this topic. http://mises.org/daily/2259

    2.There is demographic bias – USA accept (un)officially millions of immigrants from poor countries, which lower the overall wealth standard. Scandinavian countries are not facing this ‘problem’

    @Manthan Batt: You compare Venezuela with crime, corruption and drugs riddled Colombia. I would suggest you to compare it with Chile. Or better example – compare the social situation in Taiwan/China or North/South Korea.

  8. nice article, i loved it! it is a great comparison of wasting money on an ideal that has no basis(ie. tax cuts/tax rebates). but the premise that the overall transfer of wealth determines the more “social-democratic” a state is not correct. liberal economies use taxes to distribute wealth, while social democratic states use public programs (ie. More mass transportation, single payer health systems, free day-care, etc.). it is obvious by this comparison that using taxes to distribute wealth is ridiculous(which sort-of implies that the poor aren’t very good with money(it might be obvious to say this and a little harsh but it destroys the basis of liberal economist of rational players)). essentially,” tax and spend” is good while “tax and give back” fails.
    +1

  9. The one thing the is failed to be reported in this study is the fact that social spending tends to hurt those it is designed to help, keeping them in overty rather than getting them out of it.

  10. Employment-based health insurance and pensions don’t cover the poorest, which seems like the operative issue.

Leave a Reply